not on those grounds. The defense team knew that it was basically charging a rental fee for space that belonged to the public. They also knew they would never get away with that defense. Instead, they argued that the revenue from the parking meters, and the inevitable tickets, was to pay for parking enforcement.â
I thought that one over a moment. It was very twisted logic.
âAnd they won with that argument?â
âIndeed.â
âWait, let me get this straight. We feed the meterââ
âA device none of us asked for,â Philo said. âNor were we consulted over their placement.â
âRight. We feed the meter to pay someone to patrol the meter we didnât ask for and give us a ticket if we park beside it for too long. That doesnât make any sense.â
âNo. It doesnât. But thatâs how parking meters overcame their first legal challenge and weâve been tossing nickels, dimes and quarters into their gaping maw ever since. That little tidbit is lost to history. And now that the legality is essentially out of the way, city councils all across the country have a number of ersatz reasons for sticking a meter alongside any spot big enough to park a car.â
âSuch as?â
âTurnover. Force people to move their cars so others can park. Of course, thatâs only valid in shopping areas so it doesnât explain the prevalence of meters in every part of town.â
He picked up his tea, sipped it and set the cup back down.
âForcing people onto public transportation is another dubious reason given for the parking meterâs existence, though that, too, is ludicrous. In most metropolitan areas, public transportation either doesnât exist in any meaningful way or, where it does, is wholly inadequate for the needs of the communities it serves. This inadequacy leads to frustration, which leads to more people driving, which leads to less revenue, which leads to further deterioration of service ⦠and on and on in a downward spiral.
âThe problem, of course, is that if people drive, they must park. For them to park, there must be parking places. On average, a person works eight hours a day. You donât find many eight-hour parking meters: Thirty minutes, sixty, two hours tops. It doesnât compute and this is where the whole theory of metered parking falls apart.â
âFall apart? â I said. âIâm not sure I understand that.â
âItâs simple, really. As with anything, there is an obvious cost and a hidden cost. With metered parking, the hidden cost is quite high. Now, the obvious cost is the meter itself; its installation and maintenance and, of course, all the people necessary to run a department of parking enforcement, including those who check the meters and write the tickets. This cost is borne by the revenue produced by the meters and the tickets, roughly twenty percent of gross.â
âAnd the hidden cost?â
âBusinesses carry the brunt of that,â he said. âAnd then there is the issue of lost space.â
âLost space?â
âYes. You see, the state mandates the size of a metered parking space, pretty much to accommodate the largest vehicle that might park there, plus several feet fore and aft. But not everyone has large cars, especially in this day of escalating fuel prices. What this means is, a Volkswagen is allotted as much room as a Cadillac. On a city block with ten meters, only ten cars can park. Without those meters, you could likely squeeze in thirteen, maybe fourteen cars. Because the block is metered, nearly twenty-five percent of that block is lost to parking space.â
âOkay. What about the loss to business?â
âEasy. Two-hour parking meter. Eight-hour day. Anyone parked at a meter will have to run out to their car three, possibly four times a day. More if they get a meter with less time. Figure ten to twenty minutes each
A. M. Riley
PJ Nunn
Victor Pelevin
Mary Higgins Clark
Stef Penney
Nan Rossiter
Unknown
Anna Schmidt
Erica James
Marie Coulson